Blog2017-06-03T09:45:07-07:00

Financial sector compensation

As the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission cranks up and begins to look at substantive issues, you can expect me to begin commenting more frequently on financial policy issues. I expect that my thinking will evolve as I learn more over fourteen months in the Commission’s lifetime, so please don’t be surprised when you see that reflected in my posts. I may also test out some positions and ask for suggestions as I do below.

Senate Majority Leader Reid’s floor speech last Monday attracted my attention. Titled “Wall Street Narrowmindedness,” it is a broadside attack on the financial sector from the fourth most powerful person in Washington (Bernanke is #2.)

It is tempting to dismiss Leader Reid’s remarks as opportunistic demagoguery, but they forced me to think harder about my views on this important topic. I will follow each of his views with my comments. I am paraphrasing his arguments except where I use quotation marks.

Sen. Reid (paraphrased): People on Wall Street were and still are greedy.

Yes, many of them act that way. That shouldn’t surprise anyone. Our system assumes people will work in their own self-interest, on Wall Street and throughout the country. If doing so results in bad outcomes, then it’s the rules that are messed up, not people’s behavior. Any policy based on the presumption that people will say, “No, stop, you’re paying me too much” is naive and won’t work. Policies need to assume that in compensation decisions most people will generally act as if they are greedy, and channel those base instincts toward an ultimate good. That’s the whole invisible hand thing.

Sen. Reid: They are still paying themselves enormous compensation packages, but now in part with taxpayer dollars.

This is the hard one for me because it gets into multiple and conflicting roles of government. As a general rule I believe government should stay out of compensation negotiations between labor and management. I hate getting the government involved in anyone’s compensation, but there are conflicting policy goals when taxpayer funds are involved. There are countless examples of the government appropriately imposing restrictions on firms when it acts as a purchaser using taxpayer funds rather than as an impartial rule maker. The USG now acts as an investor in TARP banks, Fannie, Freddie, and AIG, and it seems reasonable for an investor to place requirements on the firms in which it invests. The same logic would apply to GM and Chrysler. Those requirements can, in my view, include reasonable compensation limits. This is easier when those investments are supposed to be temporary.

But this view leads me to two problems:

  • an unwinding problem: Some (probably on the left) may be tempted to leave the taxpayer funds in the firm so they can continue the limitations. If we have to invest, as I believe we did with TARP, I want both the investments and the rules to be temporary, and to set up a system where the firms are encouraged to repay the taxpayer and remove the restrictions as quickly as possible. This is what we tried to do with TARP.
  • two slippery slope problems: By crossing the line and saying I’m OK with compensation limits in this case, I have to differentiate it from other cases where some on the left will argue for compensation limits. Sen. Rockefeller, for instance, tried to limit the compensation of health insurers in a Finance Committee markup. In addition, I don’t think the government should be telling these firms how and to whom they should lend, but the line quickly gets fuzzy.

Sen. Reid: The structure of their compensation packages is encouraging them to jeopardize the financial system … to swing for the fences and make deals that put their entire firms and the larger system at risk.

This is the “excessive risk” argument, which I don’t feel I understand well enough. Some people argue that certain derivatives and trading contributes little economic value and therefore “should not” be rewarded. My instinct is that this is a decision for the firm’s managers … if they want to reward their employees for something that is non-economic, that’s their mistake to make. If instead this non-economic behavior is benefiting the firm owners and employees only by shifting risk to the taxpayer, then I want to know what policies allow or create incentives for this behavior, and then look at fixing those rules, instead of coming in on the back end and clumsily limiting compensation.

I wish someone could show me a specific compensation package which leads to firm-jeopardizing and system-jeopardizing behavior. And I don’t understand how the government should define “excessive.” I could use some help here if anyone has it.

Sen. Reid: Financial sector employees should not get compensation so much larger than that of an average American worker, especially when the economy is weak.

This is just scary. With “financial sector employees” he’s talking about an entire industry. Senator Reid is saying Washington should determine relative compensation levels among industries. I don’t think John Travolta should have been paid $10M for his role in Battlefield Earth: A Saga of the Year 3000, the same year the .com bubble was bursting, but I also don’t think it’s Washington’s role to make that call.

Sen. Reid: We must put an end to the recklessness that got us into this mess.

I agree in theory, but am concerned that his definition of “recklessness” is too broad. If it incorporates all the previous concepts, including generalized greed and his notion that government should set relative compensation levels, then I’m not onboard. If “recklessness” is only excess compensation that encourages system-jeopardizing risk-taking, then I’m open to a discussion if those concepts can be precisely defined.

Sen. Reid: He supports Treasury’s rules to limit compensation for TARP recipients. He also supports the Fed’s announcement that it will rein in banks that reward the riskiest practices … gambles that endanger all of us.

I have covered these above. I am uncomfortable but can live with compensation limits for TARP recipients. I need to study how the Fed proposes to “rein in banks that reward the riskiest practices.” I am open to the concept subject to understanding and being comfortable with the details, but I hope there’s a way we can do it other than through compensation limits.

Sen. Reid: In upcoming legislation, We will make sure banks are compensating their employees in a prudent way. That means firms won’t be able to throw cash at a trader who closes a big, risky deal … one that puts the whole bank at risk and that threatens taxpayers and the greater financial system as well.

It’s interesting that he says banks here, rather than Wall Street more generally. What is the policy interest in how a small non-TARP Midwestern community bank pays its CEO? Or would Sen. Reid’s limits apply only to large banks with trading desks that pose risks to the financial system, as suggested by his second sentence? And is he concerned with compensation of all bank employees, or only of big traders?

Sen. Reid: Wall Street has to take responsibility for its own actions also. So these firms whether or not they owe the government for their survival should be careful about what their actions say about them because the American people are listening closely.

This is a bald-faced threat to all of Wall Street: firms “whether or not they owe the government for their survival should be careful” to “be careful about what their actions say about them.” This kind of vague but direct threat is highly inappropriate for a leading policymaker.


So here’s my DRAFT position:

  1. Government should generally not be involved in compensation decisions.
  2. When government has invested billions of taxpayer dollars in a firm, it is OK for government to set limits on compensation levels to protect the taxpayer. Ideally both the investment and limits are temporary.
  3. If it can be shown that certain compensation structures significantly exacerbate risk to the financial system, then it is OK for government to set limits on these compensation structures, but better to consider policies directed at the risky behaviors directly. Depending on the details I may be able to live with the former, but prefer the latter if possible.

I really don’t like #2, but I cannot find a principle that makes me less uncomfortable. Striking #2 would conflict with a gut common sense that taxpayer funds should not support huge compensation packages. It may be that the conflicting goals of noninterference and taxpayer protection cannot be cleanly reconciled.

A friend makes a convincing case that accounting rules and bank practices create a mismatch in which certain employees have been and are paid for shifting risks onto the taxpayer. If he’s right, then we should try to fix those mismatches directly. That’s the concept in #3. Leaving the mismatches in place and instead changing the compensation structures is a kludge.

I invite suggestions from readers for alternative positions, especially on #2. In firms in which the taxpayer has invested billions of dollars, what should be the government’s role in compensation structures and levels? (Rants and SHOUTING about greedy b******s will be ignored or deleted. I’m looking for reasoned logic, please, not table-pounding.)


I will close with a question and caution of my own for Wall Street: Why do boards structure compensation packages that appear to reward failed firm leaders with generous exit packages? I understand that some private equity firms include clawback provisions in their compensation to address this situation. Why don’t other financial firms do this?

Excepting the recent TARP situation, most policymakers I know (other than those on the far left) are quite comfortable when successful firm leaders get high financial compensation commensurate with their contribution to the firm’s success. But when they see a headline, “Fired CEO X leaves with $Y million,” it puts these elected officials in a really tough position if they are asked a question by a reporter. Yes, I understand that much of that $Y million is deferred compensation. It doesn’t have to be deferred. And when you (corporate board members) put free market officials in an indefensible position, you make it much harder for them to defend a hands-off approach to compensation policies.

A factory worker who is fired for poor performance generally doesn’t get a huge exit package. Why does the CEO?

(photo credit: I’m not hungry – I’m just greedy by CaptPiper)

Monday, 2 November 2009|

No job growth for eight months?

On CBS’ Early Show today, Vice Presidential Economic Advisor Jared Bernstein emphasized the Administration’s new estimates that the stimulus has “saved or created” one million jobs. I won’t belabor the point that these estimates are unreliable.

But in a classic example of burying the lead, Dr. Bernstein was asked when he expected job growth.

Harry Smith: When does this economy start to create jobs on its own?

Dr. Bernstein: As far as the overall economy is concerned, private sector forecasters tell us that by the second half of next year, net job growth should be positive, unemployment should be coming down.

I hope this is expectations management. The beginning of the second half of next year is eight months away.

Here’s the follow-up question I’d like to see asked:

If these projections are correct and the economy loses jobs for the next eight months, how certain is economic recovery?

See for yourself, beginning at 02:38.

Watch CBS News Videos Online

Friday, 30 October 2009|

CBO weighs in on the health bills

If you have been following my health posts closely over the past few months, then you should be ready for this analysis from CBO: Different Measures for Analyzing Current Proposals to Reform Health Care.

This is only for budding policy wonks who want to test their newfound comprehension of the arcane world of health budgeting.

I offer my compliments to Director Elmendorf and the CBO health team for this analysis. It is a fine example of how CBO has this year gone beyond what is strictly required of them and offered analysis to policymakers to make sure they really understand what they’re doing. If only more lawmakers would read it.

I offer three observations.

  1. CBO says that both bills would reduce the budget deficit in the short run and in the long run, but suggests they do so only by making Medicare payment changes that “may be” (I say are) politically unsustainable. Senator Reid tried to be hypocritical last week when he attempted to pass a freestanding bill to increase Medicare spending on doctors at the same time the health reform bill allows “cuts” to take effect. A majority of the Senate did the right thing and slapped this down.The House is headed down this same path. Because of the Speaker’s control over the rules, she is more likely to be successful in passing this hypocrisy. Question for those Blue Dog Democrats who will vote for the Speaker’s bill “because CBO says it reduces the deficit”: how do you justify the deficit-increasing impact of the combination of that bill with the doctor payment-increase bill? If the separate “doc fix” bill passes the House, whether or not you vote for it, then your vote for the Speaker’s health reform bill is a vote to increase the deficit.
  2. The last table in CBO’s analysis is instructive. It shows that the Senate Finance Committee bill slightly reduces the “federal budgetary commitment to health care” over a 10-year period. In contrast the House bill dramatically increases this commitment, by $598 B over 10 year and by $104 billion in the year 2019. That latter figure is enormous for a single year effect. The House bill reduces the deficit only by raising non-health taxes by a greater amount.How, then, can the President and his budget director argue that “health care reform is entitlement reform?” The good case (Senate bill) is one where the long-term federal commitment to health care is essentially unchanged. In the bad case (House bill), Congress would be massively increasing its budgetary commitment to health while raising unrelated taxes to hide it. If either of these bills become law, future entitlement spending pressures are far more likely to be addressed by enormous tax increases, including on the middle class. A vote for either bill is a vote to raise future taxes on the middle class.
  3. Kudos to CBO for this commitment at the end: “Finally, the question of what impact proposals might have on health insurance premiums is also of considerable interest. CBO intends to address that issue in the near future.” I can’t wait.CBO:
    • I hope you will incorporate the concepts embodied in Amy Finkelstein’s research in this analysis. Increased insurance coverage >> increased utilization of medical care >> higher health insurance premiums.
    • I also hope you will continue the precedent you established in the late 1990s when CBO estimated the effects on private health insurance premiums of mandates. CBO used to estimate that mental health parity mandates would increase private health insurance premiums. They made similar estimates for versions of the Patients’ Bill of Rights. You should do the same for these bills, in particular the effects of guaranteed issue and modified community rating on average private health insurance premiums. For this to be useful to policymakers, I hope you analyze separately the employer-sponsored and individual/exchange markets.
    • I hope you also show the effects of these premium changes on wages. After all, you and JCT need to do so to estimate the effects on the taxable wage base, no?

(photo credit: balance by hans s)

Friday, 30 October 2009|

Updating the legislative scenarios: Reply hazy, ask again later

Now that Speaker Pelosi has released her health bill and Leader Reid will soon release his, we near the end of the most opaque part of the legislative process and approach floor consideration of both bills.

In response to yesterday’s post, a friend with two decades of legislative experience commented that this is the most interesting legislative process in years. I agree, and it is also quite difficult to predict. I just wish this fascinating process did not involve a policy that could so severely damage our economy.

Usually a legislative process gets easier to predict as it proceeds. This one is more difficult, and I am less certain about my projections than I was a month ago. At a minimum, I hope to help identify the forces pushing for and against legislative success.

Enactment of a comprehensive law is far from certain. The last two attempts to enact major health care reform both failed: the Clinton Health Plan in 1994, and the Patients’ Bill of Rights about ten years ago. PBoR seemed inevitable right up to when it died.

Here are my updated projections:

  1. Cut a bipartisan deal on a comprehensive bill with 3 Senate Republicans, leading to a law this year; (0.1% -> 0.01%)
  2. Pass a partisan comprehensive bill through the House and through the regular Senate process with 60, leading to a law this year; (unchanged at 50%)
  3. Pass a partisan comprehensive bill through the House and through the reconciliation process with 51 Senate Democrats, leading to a law this year; (20% –> 10%)
  4. Fall back to a much more limited bill that becomes law this year; (24.9% -> 10%)
  5. No bill becomes law this year. Process continues into next year. (5% -> 29.99%)

I am therefore now projecting a 60% chance a comprehensive bill becomes law this year a decline from 70% almost a month ago. This is largely due to the slow pace of legislative progress. I believe the job gets harder the longer it takes.

The end of the legislative year approaches. This process has moved slowly enough that I no longer think there is time to “pivot” from failure of a comprehensive bill to passage of an incremental bill this year. If Democrats are still struggling in December to pass a bill through the Senate, I think it’s far more likely the process just drags on into next year. This is why I shifted the 30% “failure this year” scenarios from “pivot this year” (option 4) to “drag into next year” (option 5). Scenario (5) might next year lead to any of scenarios (2), (3), or (4).

Let’s examine the forces in favor of a comprehensive bill this year:

  • Democrats have made significant legislative progress. Speaker Pelosi and Leader Reid each have a bill to which they are attaching their own names, and those bills roughly represent variants of the committee products within each body. That lends legitimacy to their bills (at least within the Democratic caucus) and creates an initial presumption among most Democrats in favor of these bills. If you’re a Democratic member, you will need to explain to your leaders, the White House, and your colleagues why you’re choosing to oppose the leader’s bill. This burden of proof creates a psychological advantage in favor of passage.
  • The Democratic party is unified in wanting a major legislative accomplishment. I know of no Democrat who is saying he or she wants the bill to fail, even if some of them will vote against it. This sounds trivial but is important. Congressional Democrats appear to believe that enactment of a comprehensive law is critical to their re-election. Most seem to believe that a White House signing ceremony is more important than the contents of the bill that becomes law. This helps the Leaders and the President rally votes and creates legislative bargaining flexibility.
  • The bill would appear to achieve a core policy goal of covering millions of uninsured. This is a policy holy grail for many Democrats.
  • It appears they can get CBO to say the bills, as drafted, are deficit-neutral. If so, this can assuage many concerns from nervous Democratic members. Jim Capretta and I have each written about why these bills will in fact still increase the deficit, but in the vote-counting context, CBO’s stamp of approval is a critical advantage.
  • The President and his team appear highly flexible on policy. Other than insisting that the bill not increase the budget deficit, the Administration appears willing to accommodate almost any policy changes needed to get the votes. The bills being developed would increase private health insurance premiums for most and bend the private cost curves up, but you don’t hear the White House protesting. It’s easier to get a bill when you don’t care too much what’s in it. They can rationalize this behavior by saying they are focused on the broad brush strokes of policy. Unfortunately, these bills get key broad strokes wrong, most importantly by increasing health care costs rather than reducing them.
  • The President and his team appear willing to use the President’s considerable resources to get votes. The President has a lot of resources he can bring to bear to persuade wavering members. He can support policy changes, make public statements, support or oppose other legislation, use administrative policy to make unrelated changes. He can commit his officials to visiting a particular Congressional district. He can help Democratic members get favorable press coverage back home. He can promise pork barrel spending in a district  I expect to soon see hospital-specific earmarks. He can invite Members to the Oval or on Air Force One for a personal pitch. He can raise money for candidates.

At the same time, there are factors making it harder to enact a law this year.

  • The public option fight slows down the bill. I think the public option fracas is overrated, mostly because there is a lot of policy room for potential compromise among Democrats. We have seen some of this already, and I just don’t believe that liberals will kill a bill that provides >95% health insurance coverage because the public option is “too weak.” But this intra-party battle consumes leader time and energy, making it harder to resolve other problems as they crop up.
  • With one exception, Republicans are unified in their opposition. Six months ago this was not a foregone conclusion. Republican leaders have been effective in unifying their party, facilitated by a legislative process that shut them out. I have written before that the President could have had a bipartisan bill, had he empowered Chairman Baucus to negotiate on his behalf with Finance Committee Republicans. The President implicitly chose to make this process partisan, and in so doing helped unify Republican opposition.
  • Tick, tock, tick, tock… Speaker Pelosi says she wants to move a bill quickly in the House (within the next two weeks, meaning the House is done before Thanksgiving). As usual the Senate is moving more slowly. This slow schedule means the elections and Thanksgiving recess can affect the Senate debate. If VA or NJ Governors’ races go Republican, will that scare a few Democratic Members into voting no? Expect lots of partisan spin from both sides next Wednesday about how the election results affect legislative prospects.
  • Oh yeah. The voters. More interesting is the Thanksgiving break. Will citizens besiege Members the way they did in August? Assuming the House has already passed a bill, will citizen input affect votes in the Senate? I hope so.
  • Moving forward without the votes. Both Leaders appear to be introducing bills and starting their legislative clocks before knowing they have the votes locked up. Sometimes you have to do this, but it’s risky. It also exposes the vote-gathering process to a moderate amount of sunlight, which is good for citizens but difficult for those whipping the votes. The leaders control the timing of when their respective floor debates begin. This means they can wait until they think they have the votes before proceeding. On the other hand, if they wait too long they could start losing votes, or they could run out of time on the back-end.
  • How to proceed on the Senate floor? Does Leader Reid allow a full amendment process, which could consume four weeks and might fragment his not-yet-existant coalition? Or does he quickly invoke cloture or “fill the amendment tree,” blocking unfriendly Republican amendments at the cost of exposing himself to process abuse attacks? Both paths involve significant risk.
  • Reconciliation is much harder now. By choosing a regular order path, Leader Reid is gambling he can hold 60 votes on key votes. In theory he still has reconciliation as a fallback process path, but the optics of doing reconciliation after you’ve been unable to hold your own party together are terrible. This is why I have lowered my projection for this path from almost 25% to 10%. If Reid can’t get to 60 votes, the entire effort is in big trouble.
  • Private health insurance premiums for 100+ M Americans would go UP. I know I’m harping on this, but it’s hard to think of a more important effect. I am encouraged that opponents of the bill are making this point – I have seen or heard it from Leader Boehner, Leader McConnell, and Senators Grassley and Enzi. If the debate turns to these quantitative aspects of the bill, and if Congressional Democrats start worrying that they are voting for bills that make health insurance more expensive for many, then the probability of enactment will decline precipitously.

In a couple of weeks I’ll shake the Magic 8-Ball and ask again.

* Technically, this post title blends two Magic 8-Ball answers: “Reply hazy, try again” and “Ask again later.”

(photo credit: Will I Ever Make Explore? (75/365) by somegeekintn)

Thursday, 29 October 2009|

Five important upcoming Senate health care votes

I’m back after a hiatus. Leader Reid dominated the health news this week with his announcement that the bill he will bring to the Senate floor will contain the public option. This is an important but overrated issue. Still, it is dominating the tactical planning and vote counting, so let’s examine the upcoming Senate floor situation.

I have the benefit of a helpful friend who has helped me anticipate the legislative action. Much of this post is based on that friend’s input.

Remember that Leader Reid has complete control over the text of the bill he brings to the Senate floor. As a formal matter he can put anything he wants into the bill. This is a primary element of the power of the Senate Majority Leader – he gets to determine the base text of any bill being debated.

As a practical matter, Leader Reid wants his bill to pass the Senate, which tremendously limits his flexibility. He is playing with a universe of 61 potential votes (59 Ds + Independent Lieberman + Republican Snowe), of which he will sometimes need 60. That’s an enormously difficult task because any 2 of those 61 working together can hold him hostage. If Leader Reid pushes Senator Snowe away, then any one D can leverage him.

Here are important votes to watch when the Senate begins debate, in a reasonable possible chronological order.

<

ol>

  • Cloture on the motion to proceed – Reid needs a majority (51) to pass the motion to proceed so the Senate can begin debating and amending the bill. If Republicans filibuster this motion, he will need 60 votes to invoke cloture and shut off debate. Members of the majority party traditionally stick with the leader on all votes related to the motion to proceed. If a D or Sen. Lieberman threatens to vote no on this cloture vote, then the bill is in huge trouble. If cloture is invoked on the motion to proceed, then the vote to adopt the motion to proceed becomes routine.Sen. Lieberman’s recent comments suggest he will support cloture on the motion to proceed, but may oppose cloture on the bill (step 4 or 5 below). And Republicans may not even filibuster the motion to proceed. One can argue that the best way to kill a bad bill is to get on that bill quickly (and avoid looking obstructionist by granting the motion to proceed) and start offering amendments. The motion to proceed may be a non-event.
  • One or more votes to waive the Budget Act – If the bill in any way violates the numeric requirements set forth in the budget resolution, then a Senator (almost certainly a Republican, and a safe bet would be Budget Committee Ranking Republican Judd Gregg) could raise a budget point of order that would kill the Reid amendment. Reid can avoid this ifhe gets all the numbers right (very difficult). The politics of building a compromise among 60 Senators may, however, force him to spend more money than the budget resolution allows, or at different times than it allows. If so, he will have no choice but to violate the Budget Act. In this scenario he will need 60 votes to waive the Budget Act.The Baucus/Finance Committee bill appeared to fit within the budget resolution parameters. This is unsurprising since the most experienced budget staffer on Capitol Hill works for Chairman Baucus. Will Reid’s version be as rigorous?
  • A motion to strike or amend the public option – I assume someone will try to strike (delete) or amend (change) the public option part of Reid’s amendment. Assume all 40 Rs would support such an amendment. Q: How many Ds support it?If 9 or fewer Ds support it, then the amendment fails and the public option as drafted by Reid remains in the bill.If 10 Ds support it, then it’s a 50-50 tie, to be broken by Vice President Biden, who is also President of the Senate. If he votes no, then the amendment still fails.If the VP would or might vote aye, or if there are 11 or more Ds supporting the amendment, then things get really interesting. A majority of the Senate would support changing the bill, but the overwhelming majority of those who would be expected to vote for final passage would oppose such a change. I would expect liberals (like Sen. Rockefeller) to filibuster the amendment, forcing the center-right to get 60 votes to invoke cloture on their filibuster. They won’t be able to do so.

    This could provoke a stalemate within the Democratic party, in which liberals refuse to allow a majority of the Senate (all Rs + maybe 11 Ds) to strike or change the public option, and moderate Ds refuse to support cloture on the Reid substitute amendment (see step 4) unless their amendment is adopted.

  • Cloture on the Reid substitute amendment – I anticipate Leader Reid will move to proceed to a “shell bill,” some random tax bill already passed by the House (so he doesn’t run into a Constitutional problem). If the motion to proceed is adopted, he would then take his proposal and offer it as a complete substitute amendment to the bill. As a technical procedural matter, the Senate will then debate and try to amend the “Reid substitute
    [amendment].” At some point, Leader Reid will try to shut off the debate and amendment process by filing a cloture motion on his amendment. He will need 60 votes to invoke cloture, and this is probably the determinative vote for success or failure. If he gets 60 votes or more to invoke cloture on his substitute, then adopting the substitute amendment is straightforward (he needs only 51). The fourth step likely becomes routine as well.
  • Cloture on the bill as amended by the Reid amendment – If his substitute amendment is adopted, there will be other procedural opportunities for opponents to slow down or block the bill. Reid will need to file cloture on the underlying bill as amended by the Reid substitute amendment. He will again need 60 to invoke cloture and 51 for final passage.
  • The Senate has a long tradition of compromise. The public option is not a binary policy choice. There is a spectrum of options available, if Democratic Senators are willing to work together and compromise. It is quite easy to imagine a stalemate leading to a White House-brokered compromise among Democrats to facilitate steps 4 and 5. I don’t like this scenario because I oppose the underlying bill and hope it dies, but one should not assume that Sen. Lieberman’s stated opposition, for instance, draws a bright line.

    I will soon update my projections.

    (photo credit: U.S. Senate Historical Office)

    Wednesday, 28 October 2009|

    The jobs battle

    The President’s advisors are devoting a lot of communications effort to framing the employment picture. The “jobs battle” is likely to continue as a first-tier economic and political issue through 2010. Here is some context on the intersection among the economics, the policy, and the politics. I have written much of this before but thought it might be useful to summarize it in one place.

    • U.S. employment continues to decline, albeit much more slowly than at the beginning of 2009.
    • Declining more slowly is not the same as increasing. The President’s team wanted to trumpet good news as early as possible and they jumped the gun. A few weeks ago they had to adjust their message (again) to a less optimistic one. This was a communications mistake, not a policy one.
    • Employment growth will return. We just don’t know when, and the when is critical economically and politically.
    • Most forecasters expect a strong Q3 GDP number, to be released Thursday, October 29th. The two big questions are: (1) will that GDP growth be sustained through 2010, and (2) will it translate into job growth? The fiscal stimulus is temporary, and needs to translate into job growth and consumption growth to be sustainable.
    • It is normal for employment not to grow at the beginning of a recovery. As demand for their products begins to increase, employers typically make their employees work longer hours before hiring new workers. Once the increased demand looks stable and predictable, and once the current workforce is working as much as they can, then employers start hiring. First you increase hours per worker, then you increase the number of workers.
    • I recommend watching two numbers:
      1. the unemployment rate – It was 9.8% in September. Most economists consider about 5% to be “full employment.” When will it begin to decline, and how long will it take to regain full employment?
      2. the net change in payroll employment – This was -263,000 in September. First this needs to turn positive. Second, since the labor force grows with population, this number needs to reach +100K to +150K per month to keep up with population growth and keep the unemployment rate constant. Finally, it needs to exceed this range for the unemployment rate to decline toward 5%.
    • The press is paying a lot of attention to a third statistic, the U-6 measure of unemployment + underemployment. It’s an interesting and politically significant statistic, because it’s so much bigger than the traditional unemployment rate metric. But so far I don’t think it tells us a lot more about the trends than the above two metrics.
    • I will begin to feel good about the employment picture when we have had two consecutive months of payroll numbers >100K. At the same time you would expect the unemployment rate to start declining. I think the most important question you can ask an economic forecaster right now is, “When do you think the unemployment rate will begin to decline?”
    • Job growth was slow to start in the 2003-2004 recovery. You may remember the political attacks from the left about the “jobless recovery” in the 2004 campaign. The recent severe recession was cause by a financial shock. Economists have widely dispersed views on two questions:
      • Did the jobless recovery of 2003-2004 signal a fundamental change in the pace of job growth in a “normal” recovery?
      • Will the somewhat unusual cause of this recession affect the pace of job growth in the recovery?
    • There is even more uncertainty than normal in projecting near-term job growth. I generally treat economic forecasts more than 12 months out as wild guesses. This year I have shortened that window to 6 months. I don’t think anyone has a clue what the employment picture will look like 9 or 12 months from now.
    • This uncertainty makes it hard for businesses to plan. Consumer spending is about 70% of GDP, and the most important determinants of consumption are (1) how many people are working and (2) are their paychecks going up?
    • Some on the right argue the fiscal stimulus is not helping increase economic growth. That’s silly. The government is pushing hundreds of billions of dollars out the door. At least in the short run, that’s going to increase GDP growth. We should see some of that effect in the Q3 GDP numbers nine days from now. The fiscal stimulus should continue to help increase GDP growth above what it otherwise would have been into and through most of 2010, especially in the first half.
    • I believe the stimulus is helping boost GDP growth now above what it otherwise would have been, but that it is too late, poorly designed, and horribly inefficient and wasteful. They are getting some bang, but their bang-for-the-buck and effectiveness are terrible.
    • At the same time, the Administration irresponsibly overstates and overspecifies the employment impact of the fiscal stimulus.
      • Their “jobs created or saved” numbers are claims, not measures. Since we can’t know how many jobs would have been lost without policy changes, we can’t measure the change that policies have caused.
      • This means they cannot prove their statements about the number of jobs saved or created by policy, and critics cannot prove those statements are incorrect. This lack of verifiability, and the vulnerability of these statistics to political bias, allow the Administration flexibility to adjust their claimed success to meet political demands. It is irresponsible for an Administration to use these numbers as definitive, and irresponsible for the press to report them without heavy caveats.
      • Every time I hear “
        [number] jobs saved or created,” I ignore the number and assume I am being spun. This is particularly true when the numbers are specific, e.g., “250,000 education jobs saved or created.” I think this is irresponsible and misleading. It feels like they’re just making these numbers up. Reading the methodology behind the numbers only reaffirms this view.
      • The fiscal stimulus is one of several policy moves contributing to stronger (or less weak) economic growth. The Fed’s and Treasury’s actions (begun last September) to stabilize large financial institutions and financial markets helped a lot. The Fed is also keeping interest rates extremely low. Administration officials routinely attribute all of the unmeasurable economic benefit to one of three major policy changes. This is invalid.
    • Given the above caveats about unpredictability, the Administration’s forecast for 2010 is gloomy. The Administration forecasts an unemployment rate hovering in the high 9s throughout 2010. If they’re right, there will be a period where net job growth will be slightly positive (say, 100K-150K jobs per month) and the unemployment rate will be inching downward. This could create a dangerous political dynamic, in which the Administration and Congressional Democrats will be tempted to argue that things are getting better, but where it won’t feel like they’re getting better because the unemployment rate is still so high.
    • If this economic forecast plays out, it will pose an interesting question for the 2010 Congressional elections. Which is a more important determinant of how Americans vote: the level of unemployment, or the direction and rate of change? It’s possible that next November things will still be bad, but getting slowly better. Will voters punish the party in power for the level, or reward them for the change underway?
    • Elected officials in both parties correctly think their rhetorical efforts can affect how voters view the economy. Expect the political jobs battle to continue for another year.

    (photo credit: JThomasShaw)

    Tuesday, 20 October 2009|

    Regional inequities in health care reform

    In the pending health care bills, low-income individuals and families who buy health insurance outside employment will get large government subsidies. Those subsidies vary by locale. This represents a significant implicit policy decision with enormous distributional and political consequences. I don’t think most Members or their constituents have focused on this. I think they should.

    Let’s start with the Knights, a family of four with adults age 40. The family has $44,000 of income, putting them at twice the poverty line for a family of that size. The Knights do not get health insurance through their employer. The Knight family lives in Las Vegas.

    Their friends the Ford family are identical in every way, except they live in Portland, Maine. They, too, make $44,000 of income, but it doesn’t go quite as far as the Knights’ $44K, because it costs almost 6% more to live in Portland than in Las Vegas, according to CNN.com’s cost-of-living calculator. Utility costs are much higher in Portland, and food prices are 2% higher in Portland.

    Suppose we are designing a new national program to subsidize food for modest-income families. We have a range of choices.

    1. At one extreme, both families get the same subsidy amount.
    2. At the other extreme, both families pay the same net amount for groceries, meaning the Ford family gets a bigger subsidy, since groceries cost more in Portland.

    Which is fair? In a system of locally-elected representatives, your answer probably depends on where you live. I can construct legitimate arguments for either extreme, or for a midpoint policy such as the Ford family getting a 2% bigger subsidy than the Knights.

    Now what if people in Portland eat 5% more than people in Las Vegas? If we go with approach (2), should the Ford family get a subsidy that accounts for the higher prices in Maine and their greater food consumption? Should the two families pay the same amount for groceries if they’re eating different amounts? Again, there’s no objectively right answer. My personal preference is to favor approach (1).

    Different federal spending programs take each extreme approach and many variants in between. Some adjust for regional variations; others do not.


    Now let’s look at what the Baucus bill does for the new low-income subsidies to purchase health insurance outside of employment. Here is the key sentence from the conceptual description of the Senate Finance Committee-reported bill (labeled as page 27, it’s page 30 of the PDF).

    The premium credit amount would be tied to the second lowest-cost silver plan in the area where the individual resides.

    This is approach (2) (and it becomes clear it’s the extreme when you study the details). If you live in an area with relatively inexpensive health plans, low- and moderate-income people in your area will receive smaller government subsidies than their similarly-situated identical twins who live in relatively high-cost areas.

    A “health plan” is not a commodity like “a gallon of milk.” A health plan in Las Vegas is quite different from one in Portland. While the overall cost-of-living in Portland is higher, health care spending is much higher in Las Vegas. This higher health spending is a function of different prices and different usage of medical care.

    Atul Gawande wrote a much-discussed article on this topic in The New Yorker, “The Cost Conundrum:” What a Texas town can teach us about health care. There are wide geographic dispersions in medical care spending, and it cannot all be explained by different prices. While I disagree with Gawande’s policy conclusions, I recommend the article.

    Since insurance premiums ultimately reflect the cost of medical care used, insurance premiums too will vary widely from one area to the next. This brings us to the effects of the policy decision in the new health care bills.

    We are fortunate have a calculator created by the (liberal) Kaiser Family Foundation to do most of the hard work for us.

    The Kaiser calculator makes a simplifying assumption that premiums in high-cost areas will be 20% higher than in average areas, and premiums in low-cost area will be 20% lower than in average areas. That seems like a reasonable assumption to illustrate the conceptual point.

    I have chosen Las Vegas and Portland because they represent high-cost and low-cost areas respectively. Using Kaiser’s assumption, I will assume that a typical health insurance premium costs one-third less in low-cost Portland than in high-cost Las Vegas (1 – (80%/120%)) = 1/3. Note that while the overall cost-of-living in Portland is higher than in Las Vegas, per-person health spending is much lower in Portland in part because of differences in medical care usage.

    Under the Baucus/Senate Finance Committee bill, both the Ford family and the Knight family will pay only $3,070 for family health insurance after netting out their new government subsidy. That’s an incredible deal for either family.

    It also represents approach (2) described above. Both families pay the same amount, post-subsidy, for health insurance. Since (using Kaiser’s assumption) health insurance costs 1/3 less in Portland than in Las Vegas, under the Baucus bill the Knights in Vegas will get a $6,365 subsidy, while the Fords in Portland will get a $3,220 subsidy, 49% less than the Knights. (The Kaiser calculator gives me these subsidy amounts.)

    Is this fair? One family, living in a higher-cost area, gets a subsidy twice as large as the other because of differences in medical care usage in their local markets?


    The President has made a big deal about regional differences in health spending as an opportunity for making American health care more efficient while retaining high health outcomes. That’s one of the points of the Gawande article, that greater usage of medical care does not result in similar improvements in health. Minnesota is the usual example, where per person medical spending is low, while health outcomes are quite high.

    Academics have done a lot of research on this. If the New Yorker article excites you, go learn about the famous RAND Health Insurance Experiment and the Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care.

    The President’s push to address this source of inefficiency would lead one to design a new subsidy program favoring approach (1), equal subsidy amounts that are independent of regional differences in health spending. Approach (2) has the downside of directing greater subsidies toward areas of greater usage. When you subsidize something you get more of it, so if you subsidize areas with greater usage, you should expect even more usage. Whatever your view on the equity question, the Baucus/SFC choice of approach (2) will likely increase disparities in health spending and exacerbate the problem the President has correctly identified. This is inefficient and counterproductive.


    Efficiency is not, of course, the only goal of subsidy design. If my experience is any guide, most Members of Congress (and many citizens, and all local press) will care first about whether their modest-income families are being treated fairly relative to other similarly-situated families in other areas. Again this is a matter of perspective, but I think the approach chosen in both the Baucus bill and the House Energy & Commerce bill looks terribly unfair by creating such enormous disparities in subsidy amounts. To me it looks like if you’re a modest-income family in a low-health-spending area, you’re getting shafted relative to those in higher-spending areas.

    Let’s look at a few more examples, using the same example family (4 people with adults age 40, $44K income, no health insurance through their job). The Baucus bill gives this family the same after-subsidy cost for health insurance. This means:

    • If the family lives in the high-cost Bronx, Chicago, Baton Rouge, Detroit, or Las Vegas, they will get a government subsidy of $6,365 to buy health insurance.
    • A family with the same income living in average-cost St. Louis, Reno, or Delaware will get a government subsidy of $4,792. That’s 25% less than the Bronx or Chicago family.
    • A family with the same income living in low-cost Little Rock, Indianapolis, Portland, or Nebraska, will get a government subsidy of $3,220. That’s 49% less than the Baton Rouge or Detroit family.

    I ran similar numbers for the House Energy & Commerce Committee bill, the one most-discussed before the August summer recess, and got similar results. I wanted to see both the relative subsidy levels in both bills, and which parts of the country might qualify for different subsidy amounts.

    I needed a way to divide the country up into low, average, and high-cost areas. The nice people at Dartmouth have done the Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care, which extensively examines regional differences in medical care usage and prices. The Dartmouth folks break down per-capita Medicare spending by geographic area. It’s certainly not a perfect proxy for private health plan premiums, but we’re only trying to divide places up into high-average-low, so I think it works fairly well for a back-of-the-envelope exercise like this one. Fee-for-service Medicare spending tends to be highly correlated with non-Medicare spending in the same area. I end up with 134 “low cost” areas, 114 “average cost” areas, and 58 “high cost” areas.

    I’m sure a team of researchers could do a slightly better job, but I would bet their final list would look a lot like mine. To be careful, though, I think of this as an illustrative list of regional differences for this thought experiment. I do not claim these are the actual subsidy amounts for each region, because I have had to make and use some simplifying assumptions. The actual different amounts and regions could be determined only after a drawn-out and incomprehensible regulatory process months after enacting a new law. So while the following tables are necessarily educated guesses, I hope they illustrate the rough impacts that will result from this critical policy choice that no one is discussing.


    Here are the subsidy amounts for our example family for the two different bills:

    Comparison of government subsidies by geographic area

    Senate Finance

    Compared to high cost

    House E&C

    Compared to high cost

    High cost

    $8,251

    $8,911

    Average cost

    $6,365

    -$1,886
    (23% less)

    $7,025

    -$1,886
    (21% less)

    Low cost

    $4,478

    -$3,773
    (46% less)

    $5,138

    -$3,773
    (42% less)

    Family pays

    $3,070

    $2,410

     

    The above methodology produces the following areas:

    Illustrative geographic areas for varying low-income health insurance subsidies

    Low cost

    Average cost

    High cost

    gets high cost minus $3,773

    gets high cost minus $1,886

    Alabama Mobile Birmingham
    Dothan
    Huntsville
    Montgomery
    Tuscaloosa
    Alaska all
    Arizona Tuscon Mesa
    Phoenix
    Sun City
    Arkansas Little Rock
    Springdale
    Fort Smith
    Jonesboro
    Texarkana
    California Chico
    Redding
    Sacramento
    San Luis Obispo
    Santa Barbara
    Santa Rosa
    Bakersfield
    Fresno
    Modesto
    Napa
    Palm Springs
    Salinas
    San Diego
    San Francisco
    San Jose
    San Mateo
    Santa Cruz
    Stockton
    Ventura
    Alameda Cty
    Orange County
    Contra Costa
    Los Angeles
    San Bernadino
    Colorado Colorado Springs
    Fort Collins
    Grand Junction
    Pueblo
    Denver
    Greeley
    Boulder
    Connecticut Hartford Bridgeport
    New Haven
    Delaware all
    DC all
    Florida Sarasota
    Tallahassee
    Bradenton
    Clearwater
    Ft. Myers
    Gainseville
    Jacksonville
    Lakeland
    Ocala
    Orlando
    Ormond Beach
    Pensacola
    Ft. Lauderdale
    Hudson
    Miami
    Panama City
    St. Petersburg
    Tampa
    Georgia Albany
    Atlanta
    Augusta
    Columbus
    Rome
    Macon
    Savannah
    Hawaii all
    Idaho all
    Illinois Bloomington
    Peoria
    Rockford
    Springfield
    Urbana
    Aurora
    Evanston
    Melrose Park
    Blue Island
    Chicago
    Elgin
    Hinsdale
    Joliet
    Indiana Evansville
    Fort Wayne
    Indianapolis
    Lafayette
    Muncie
    South Bend
    Terre Haute Gary
    Munster
    Iowa Cedar Rapids
    Davenport
    Des Moines
    Iowa City
    Mason City
    Sioux City
    Waterloo
    Dubuque
    Kansas Topeka Wichita
    Kentucky Owensboro Covington
    Lexington
    Louisville
    Paducah
    Louisiana Houma
    Lake Charles
    New Orleans
    Alexandria
    Baton Rouge
    Lafayette
    Metairie
    Monroe
    Shreveport
    Slidell
    Maine Portland Bangor
    Maryland Salisbury
    Takoma Park
    Baltimore
    Massachusetts Springfield Boston
    Worcester
    Michigan Grand Rapids
    Marquette
    Petoskey
    St. Joseph
    Traverse City
    Kalamazoo
    Lansing
    Muskegon
    Saginaw
    Ann Arbor
    Dearborn
    Detroit
    Flint
    Pontiac
    Royal Oak
    Minnesota all
    Mississippi Hattiesburg
    Tupelo
    Gulfport
    Jackson
    Meridian
    Oxford
    Missouri Cape Girardeau
    Columbia
    Joplin
    Kansas City
    Springfield
    St. Louis
    Montana all
    Nebraska all
    Nevada Reno Las Vegas
    New Hampshire Lebanon Manchester
    New Jersey Morristown Camden
    Hackensack
    New Brunswick
    Newark
    Paterson
    Ridgewood
    New Mexico all
    New York Albany
    Binghamton
    Buffalo
    Elmira
    Rochester
    Syracuse
    Bronx
    East Long Island
    Manhattan
    White Plains
    North Carolina Asheville
    Durham
    Greensboro
    Greenville
    Charlotte
    Hickory
    Raleigh
    Wilmington
    Winston-Salem
    North Dakota all
    Ohio Akron
    Canton
    Cincinnati
    Cleveland
    Columbus
    Dayton
    Kettering
    Toledo
    Youngstown
    Elyria
    Oklahoma all
    Oregon all
    Pennsylvania Altoona
    Danville
    Erie
    Harrisburg
    Lancaster
    Sayre
    Allentown
    Johnstown
    Pittsburgh
    Reading
    Scranton
    Wilkes-Barre
    Philadelphia
    Rhode Island all
    South Carolina Columbia
    Greenville
    Spartanburg
    Charleston
    Florence
    South Dakota all
    Tennessee all
    Texas Abilene
    Bryan
    El Paso
    Longview
    Temple
    Waco
    Amarillo
    Austin
    Fort Worth
    Odessa
    San Angelo
    San Antonio
    Victoria
    Wichita Falls
    Beaumont
    Corpus Christi
    Dallas
    Harlingen
    Houston
    Lubbock
    McAllen
    Tyler
    Utah all
    Vermont all
    Virginia all
    Washington all
    West Virginia Morgantown Charleston
    Huntington
    Wisconsin Appleton
    Green Bay
    La Crosse
    Madison
    Marshfield
    Milwaukee
    Neenah
    Wausau
    Wyoming all

    Do Members of Congress understand the massive distributional policy choice they are making by supporting these bills?

    I’ll bet most of them don’t.

    (photo credit: Christopher Chan)

    Thursday, 15 October 2009|

    Higher premiums and lower wages

    The health insurance lobby, known as AHIP: America’s Health Insurance Plans, released a study last night showing that elements of the Baucus bill would make health insurance more expensive than under current law. The study is by PriceWaterhouseCoopers, and Karen Ignani, the head of AHIP, wrote a two-page memo summarizing it.

    Here’s the most damaging part of Ms. Ignani’s memo (but take it with a huge grain of salt, for reasons I will explain):

    The report makes clear that several major provisions in the current legislative proposal will cause health care costs to increase far faster and higher than they would under the current system. The report finds that the proposal “will increase premiums above what they would increase under the current system for both individual and family coverage in all four market segments for every year from 2010-2019.”

    For example, the analysis shows that the cost of the average family policy is approximately $12,300 today and will rise to:

    • $15,500 in 2013 under current law and to $17,200 if these provisions are implemented.
    • $18,400 in 2016 under current law and to $21,300 if these provisions are implemented.
    • $21,900 in 2019 under current law and to $25,900 if these provisions are implemented.

    In fact, between 2010 and 2019 the cumulative increases in the cost of a typical family policy under this reform proposal will be approximately $20,700 more than it would be under the current system.

    What the study says

    The PWC study purports to analyze “several major provisions” of the Baucus bill, not the whole bill. Specifically, PWC looks at:

    1. Combining mandates for guaranteed issue and community rating with a leaky individual mandate.
    2. Taxes on health insurers and health providers such as drug and medical device manufacturers.
    3. Whether cuts in Medicare reimbursement rates to medical care providers will be “shifted” to those buying private health insurance.
    4. The “Kerry” tax on high-cost health insurance plans.

    The study argues that the combined effects of these provisions would increase health insurance premiums across the board, and in some cases quite significantly.

    Reaction to the study

    The first two parts look decent. I lack the data to check them, but the basic analysis seems right, or at least it confirms my view of things. The Leavitt/Hubbard/Hennessey op-ed warned that insurance “reforms” that would benefit the predictably sick would also raise premiums for younger and healthier workers, and would create an incentive for you to wait to buy insurance until you get sick. PWC believes both these things would happen under the Baucus bill, based on the presumption that the individual mandate is soft and “leaky,” allowing an increasing number of people each year to avoid the mandate.

    It’s also solid to assume that taxes on insurers and medical care providers will be passed through to consumers as higher health insurance premiums.

    While doctors and hospital administrators swear by it, I have always been skeptical of the cost-shifting argument. If you believe that a hospital will raise the prices it charges privately insured patients in reaction to cuts in reimbursement rates from government programs, you must believe (1) the hospital has pricing power and (2) it has until now charged less than it could. (1) is quite plausible in some circumstances. I find (2) incredible. If someone has pricing power, I generally believe they will exert it. Are we to believe that providers of medical care were charging privately insured patients less than they could have before the cuts in government payment rates? I am happy to hear arguments on the other side.

    The PWC study assumes that medical care providers will pass through every dollar of reduced Medicare provider reimbursement rates as a dollar of higher costs to privately insured patients. That’s absurd.

    PWC assumes the Kerry tax on insurers selling high-cost health plans will be passed through to consumers. That’s a safe assumption. But they also assume that those higher costs will be distributed to those who purchase plans of any cost. That’s just silly. PWC should assume that the costs will be passed through only to those who buy high-cost plans. They also acknowledge that purchasers will change the benefits and structures of health plans to avoid the new tax, but ignore these adjustments in their calculations. Bogus.

    The study’s biggest flaw

    PWC, AHIP, and Ms. Ignani are careful to write that they are studying the effects on insurance premiums of four elements of the Baucus bill, rather than the effects of the entire Baucus bill. This gets watered down or even lost in the press coverage, and I imagine the political discussion will center around “Baucus bill makes health insurance more expensive.” Not coincidentally, AHIP opposes the four elements studied by PWC.

    I believe the Baucus bill would make health insurance more expensive, but we can’t tell this from the partial PWC study. The PWC analysis ignores three important effects of the Baucus bill:

    1. More insured people means greater demand for medical care, raising prices for both medical care and health insurance.
    2. CBO thinks competition in the exchanges will somewhat reduce premiums for those who buy health insurance outside of employment. I doubt this factor is large.
    3. The Baucus bill would subsidize the purchase of health insurance for those lower- and middle-income people who buy health insurance outside of employment.

    I believe the first factor is the most significant source of premium increase in the Baucus bill. But AHIP likes this factor, so they left it out of the study they requested of PWC.

    Chairman Baucus’ response

    Chairman Baucus’ staff is emphasizing the subsidies. This is a weak response that should make other Democratic members nervous. They are, in effect, conceding that their bill makes health insurance more expensive. Sure, it’s more expensive, but don’t worry, we subsidize a lot of people so it ends up costing them less on net.

    Once again, this confuses gross and net costs, and conflates reducing health insurance costs with shifting those costs onto others.

    This argument fails on policy and political fronts:

    • Policy: The President’s primary goal has been to slow the growth of health insurance costs. The PWC study is flawed, but its qualitative conclusions are correct: the Baucus bill would make private health insurance more expensive, not less. The bill therefore fails to achieve the President’s core policy goal.
    • Policy: Subsidies are available only to those who buy health insurance outside of employment. If the Baucus bill makes health insurance more expensive, then everyone who gets health insurance through their job loses: higher costs, lower wages, and no subsidies.
    • Politics: The last time I checked, more than 100 million people get their health insurance through their job or the job of a family member. Question for Chairman Baucus: How does your bill help a relatively young and relatively healthy worker who gets health insurance through work? Doesn’t your bill make this worker’s health insurance more expensive, and therefore cut his wages?
    • Politics: Some of those who buy health insurance outside their job would get government subsidies larger than their wage cuts, and some Congressional Democrats think this makes these people winners. I think most Americans would say they would rather not have a policy that cuts their wages by $1 and in exchange promises them a government subsidy worth slightly more than $1. I would rather keep $1 in wages than exchange them for $1.05 of government subsidies.

    The politics of this study

    The politics of this study cut both ways. The headline numbers make it harder for Democrats to vote for the bill, even though the study is weak and incomplete. The timing makes it look like AHIP is trying to kill the bill by releasing the study and new ads the day before the Finance Committee is supposed to vote.

    At the same time, nobody likes the health insurers, and Democrats may hope that Congressional Republicans “align” with AHIP so Democrats can have an easy-to-attack enemy alliance. Health insurers helped kill the Clinton Health Plan in 1994, but they are unpopular so nobody wants to be seen as their ally.

    Foolish AHIP

    AHIP’s strategy is inscrutable. If your goal is to kill the bill, fine, release a study like this the day before markup ends, and come out guns a-blazin’. But this outcome has been foreseeable for months. If AHIP’s goal was to kill this bill, they should have done this months ago.

    A much better explanation is that AHIP is trying to use this study to generate support for modifying the bill. This would be consistent with AHIP’s and Ms. Ignani’s rhetoric, and with their apparent strategy to work with the White House and Democratic Congressional majorities to support legislation and try to modify it to their liking. Ms. Ignani is a Democrat and former union official inclined to work with a Democratic President and Congress. She may also be playing strategic defense, hoping that by not directly opposing legislation she can avoid an all-out war with a White House and Congress that can hurt her members in countless ways.

    If this is still AHIP’s strategy, they still got the timing wrong. Washington Democrats are inclined to pick fights with the health insurers, and the timing of this release gives them an excuse to do so. Left-wing Democrats can use this move to justify shifting more of the policy pain to insurers, not less. We already saw an absurd “windfall profits tax” on health insurers floated last week.

    And these provisions in the Baucus bill have been telegraphed for months. Why wait so long to go public opposing them?

    Health insurers win financially if and only if final legislation includes a strong individual mandate and does not take too much directly out of health plan hides. That requires threading a tiny needle. If Ms. Ignani’s strategy backfires, she could destroy private health insurance in America.

    What Republicans should do

    Congressional Republicans should not embrace the AHIP study, but instead focus on the critical policy questions raised by it. Does the Baucus bill make health insurance more expensive? Does it cut wages for most Americans who today have employer-provided health insurance? If so, by how much?

    Republicans should ask CBO to answer these questions about the Baucus bill, and quickly. The AHIP study opens the door to this debate by framing the questions, but CBO is the only trusted source of information to answer them.

    It is important that CBO be asked the right questions. Important details can skew the answer. For instance, the Baucus bill would cause about 3 million people to lose their employer-provided health insurance. These people would end up with higher wages. The vast majority, in contrast, would see premium increases and lower wages. It is important that CBO analyze these two populations separately rather than net out the effects as they have done in their previous publications.

    The PWC study is flawed in its details, but qualitatively correct in its conclusion: the Baucus bill would make health insurance more expensive for most Americans, and in doing so would mean a wage cut for most. If CBO confirms this, the bill will die.

    (photo credit: Lift-off by aussiegall. No, it has nothing to do with the post. I just think it looks good.)

    Monday, 12 October 2009|

    Numbers matter

    Numbers are hard. Some people find them boring. It’s much simpler to debate whether illegal immigrants should receive subsidized health insurance and whether there should be a government-run health plan option. Everyone can participate in such a debate without much effort.

    But numbers matter in health care reform. I want to highlight some important numbers and economic forces in these bills that are receiving insufficient attention. If these bills become law, these numbers will significantly affect your financial well-being.

    The effect on health insurance spending

    I agree with the President that the core problem to be solved is the out-of-control growth of health insurance premiums and health spending. Any bill which fails to reduce those costs should not become law.

    I am talking about public and private health spending. Too much of the debate is focused on just the government’s balance sheet. The goal is to slow the growth of all health and health insurance spending.

    Here’s the super-simple conceptual model of what the pending bills do:

    1. The bills expand insurance coverage through a combination of subsidies and mandates enforced by tax penalties. Academic research is clear that increases in insurance coverage lead to more usage of medical care (and better health). More usage of medical care increases health spending and health insurance premiums.
    2. CBO thinks the exchanges will foster competition and reduce insurance premiums for those buying health insurance outside of employment. They also think a public option (which will almost certainly not survive the Senate) would further reduce premiums. I question some of CBO’s views on these points, but they’re the ref.
    3. The bills shift the cost of health insurance for some onto others, through large tax increases and reductions in projected Medicare spending. Shifting costs certainly does not reduce costs, and probably increases them.

    The big question is whether the effect of (1) or (2) is bigger. If (1) is bigger, then these bills will increase health spending and health insurance premiums and fail to achieve the President’s basic goal.

    I think (1) is much bigger than (2). I think (3) further increases incentives to spend more on health care and health insurance, but it may be a much smaller factor.

    Congress needs to ask CBO, “Would these bills result in an increase or decrease in total health spending, and in total health insurance spending, relative to current law?” CBO analyses have so far looked only at subcomponents of the population. Policymakers need the answer for the country as a whole. They also need to understand the effects on public and private health spending combined, and on public and private health insurance spending combined. Don’t just focus on government spending. That’s too narrow.

    I believe CBO will and should conclude that these bills would increase total health insurance spending relative to current law. I therefore believe the bills fail in the core objective defined by the President.

    In addition to the above economic point, there’s a simple Washington-based argument that reinforces my conclusion: the industries that generate income from health spending generally support these bills. They know that the government mandates will, on net, increase total spending on health care and health insurance, the opposite of the President’s correctly stated policy goal. If these bills actually reduced health spending relative to current law, the insurers, doctors, hospitals, and other medical providers would oppose them. Remember that the insurance industry champions the individual mandate. How many other industries would like the U.S. government to force you to buy their product, and then prohibit you from buying inexpensive versions of it?

    The effect on wages for those with employer-provided health insurance

    The so-called “insurance reforms” and mandated minimum actuarial values are restrictions that would increase the cost of employer-provided health insurance. I am not aware of any provision in these bills that would reduce the cost of this insurance.

    If I’m correct, then these bills mandate a wage cut for anyone with employer-provided health insurance. I believe this is a silver bullet that by itself can kill a bad bill, if CBO confirms my guess.

    Congress needs to ask CBO, “For those who have employer-provided health insurance today and would keep it under the bill, would the bill cause aggregate wages to be higher or lower than under current law?”

    They also should ask the same question for each income decile.

    One private study suggests that this kind of health law could result in real decreases in wages over time, especially for lower-wage workers.

    There is no way Members can vote to cut wages, even if some would be made better off on net through higher government subsidies.

    If CBO says a bill cuts wages, that bill dies.

    The inequity created by the firewall

    In 2016 a family with a worker worth about $48,000 in total annual compensation would get about $9,000 of subsidies for the purchase of health insurance, if their employer does not offer them coverage. If your employer offers you coverage, you are not eligible for these subsidies. The bills create a firewall intended to prevent employers from “dumping” their employees onto the subsidized system. This firewall creates an enormous inequity.

    Imagine two families in the year 2016, each with an identical worker whose total compensation is worth about $48,000. Both families are required to buy health insurance.

    Family A is offered health insurance through an employer. A “silver plan” will cost about $14,000 in 2016, squeezing out $14,000 of family A’s income and leaving $34,000 in wages.

    Family B is not offered health insurance through an employer, and therefore qualifies for about $9,000 in subsidies to buy health insurance. Family B thus has $48,000 in wages plus $9,000 in subsidies, minus $14,000 in health insurance and roughly $4,000 in higher taxes, leaving about $39,000 in wages after buying the same silver plan.

    Family B ends up roughly $5,000 better off than Family A, even though the workers are worth the same in total compensation. The family that does not get health insurance through employment is better off because it gets a big subsidy.

    This is a rough and oversimplified example. Congress needs to ask CBO and JCT for more precise calculations to better understand the unfairness they are creating between like workers.

    The incentives created by this inequity

    The above inequity creates a financial incentive for Family A and their employer to try to mimic Family B. While the legislation purports to ban this dumping, the incentive for firms to work around this firewall would be enormous.

    In addition, this inequity is politically unsustainable. The easiest solution would be for Congress to extend the $9,000 subsidy to family A. But there are many more family A’s than family B’s, and so extending the subsidy (in future legislation) would cause a federal spending blowout. Jim Capretta convincingly argues that the true economic cost of the bill, including this incentive effect, is a multiple of the official CBO estimate.

    Congress needs CBO and JCT to explain the incentives they are creating for employers to dump, and what creative paths employers might take in pursuit of that goal. Congress also needs to ask CBO what the cost would be if the subsidies targeted by these bills to only the non-employer market were also extended to the employer-based market, the likely political result of creating such an enormous inequity.

    Perverse work incentives

    When you’re designing a new government subsidy, you have to trade off between using a limit number of taxpayer dollars to help the most sympathetic target audience, and creating perverse incentives against work. The more you focus subsidies on the poor, the more efficiently you use your limited resources. But you also create a huge “cliff” effect, where those who work harder and earn more offset higher income with diminishing government subsidies.

    Jim Capretta (again) estimates the effects of the Baucus bill on a family whose gross income climbed from $24,000 to $48,000 in 2016. Health insurance subsidies would decline from about $16,000 to about $9,000, creating a new additional marginal tax rate of about 30%. Add to this the high effective marginal tax rates under current law from phasing out the earned income credit in this range, along with income and payroll taxes, and Jim says:

    (T)he effective, implicit tax rate for workers between 100 and 200 percent of the federal poverty line would quickly approach 70 percent – not even counting food stamps and housing vouchers.

    Congress needs to ask CBO and JCT to calculate the effective marginal tax rates on modest income workers and families that would result from these bills. I can’t imagine they want to create effective marginal tax rates that high, especially on workers in that wage range.

    Young and healthy subsidizing older and less healthy

    Mike Leavitt, Al Hubbard and I wrote about this topic in the Wall Street Journal last Friday. The combination of an individual mandate, guaranteed issue, and modified community rating means these bills would force younger and relatively healthier people to pay higher premiums than their expected health losses would justify, so they can cross-subsidize those with higher expected medical costs. In some cases these could result in enormous increases in insurance premiums for healthy workers in their 20s and 30s.

    Congress needs to understand the magnitude of these subsidies, and especially the higher costs that would be paid by younger Americans. It’s fun to emphasize the benefits of these policies to those with pre-existing medical conditions, but it’s irresponsible to ignore the higher costs that will be paid by others. This part is a zero-sum game.

    The affordability limit

    The Finance Committee bill contains a “hardship exemption” to the individual mandate: if health insurance costs more than X percent of your income, you are exempt from the mandate and not required to buy health insurance. The choice of X can have significant effects on the budgets of modest-income workers and their families, and on the cost to the taxpayer.

    Congress needs to understand the effects of different values of X:

    • If X is low (say, 5%), then many people will be exempt from the mandate, and the universal coverage goal farther away.
    • If X is high (say, 8%), then more people will have coverage because they’re forced to buy it, and at a higher out-of-pocket cost. These people will in effect face a regressive tax from the mandate to buy health insurance. They will be insured but will have less disposable income available for other needs.
    • The other option is to have X be high, but shift even more of the costs to other taxpayers by increasing the subsidies. This increases the cost of the bill.

    When your gross income is $40,000, the difference between a 5% limit and an 8% limit is $1,200. That’s a big deal in such an income range. Congress should know exactly what they’re doing to these workers and families. How many of them will end up insured and uninsured? How many will see their disposable income decline, and by how much?

    Delayed implementation

    The Finance Committee staff are using timing gimmicks to “game the budget window.” They are slipping implementation dates and new subsidy programs by six months here and there so that a smaller share of new government spending shows up in CBO’s measured 10-year timeframe. This has the effect of allowing them to increase total actual long-term government spending, while holding scored spending constant. The figures being tossed around casually in the press of a $8XX B bill or a $9XX B bill are misleading, because they represent spending over different timeframes. What matters are the long-term cost per year and the growth rate of that cost.

    Congress needs a lot more information

    In 1994 the Congressional Budget Office produced a comprehensive 104 page analysis of President Clinton’s health proposal. CBO has been doing yeoman’s work in this year’s pell-mell legislative process, but Members are still woefully uninformed. The President and Congressional Leaders are trying to march their Members forward without adequate information. I suspect this is in part because they fear that some well-informed Members would vote no.

    Congress should give CBO and JCT the time to do this kind of thorough analysis, so Members can understand what they are on the verge of doing to American society.

    These numbers matter.

    (Who to watch: Sen. Grassley, CBO, and Jim Capretta’s blog Diagnosis)

    (photo credit: Vintage abacuses by H is for Home.)

    Thursday, 8 October 2009|
    Go to Top